go back |
There has been a great deal of comment on the effect of automation upon employment. Those who - despite historical experience and current productivity data - take a negative view foresee mass unemployment. However, there are a near-infinity of useful tasks to be done that happen not to be monetised, and which needs state funding. If automation created wealth, and the state could lay its hands on that wealth, then the issue of unemployment for low skilled individuals need not arise.
Those last two "ifs" are, though, considerably unsure. Let's take them in order.
That question seems to be nonsensical. Automation makes manufacturing and services more efficient, extends their reach, increases their quality. Of course it creates more wealth.
Let's think about that in the context of an entire industry. The figure symbolises an industry before and after automation. The panel on the left shows the "before" picture. Firms have been stacked up in order of their unit cost of production, with their cumulative capacity running along the horizontal axis.
The market size in indicated by a vertical arrow. The marginal producer sets the price, and the industry added value is the area between the price and the individual costs of production, shown in yellow. The industry added value consists of that and the wages embedded in the cost element.
On the right, we find the same industry after automation. Insofar as technologies are similar, costs become very similar. Wages are very considerably eliminated. Automation also encourages the pursuit of scale, so the surviving firms become larger. Market volume of course increases, as shown, and it cuts the cost curve to set the now much lower price. As is evident, industry profit largely disappears. (Individual firms may do quite well, as large volumes times small margins may equal or surpass large margins but smaller volumes.)
Consider, though, what happens in aggregate. GNP is the sum of added value. But here we see that added value all but disappears, at least on these diagrams. Output increases, costs fall, quality improves but the economy does not get larger and employment falls. (This is called "commoditisation", and is a common phenomenon in ageing industries, or industries with many independent producers. Automation, in this sense, is accelerated ageing.) The implication is that whilst output may accelerate and prices may fall, sensu strictu GNP will stagnate. Profitability will be depressed, and without an option for any renewal that can be expected to last. Return on assets will be depressed, chronically, with wide ranging consequences. Amongst these:
Aspects of these consequences are already with us.
Automation can, then, have unexpected outcomes. If it proceeds quickly, and with some universality, it can destroy industry profitability. (Cost cutting in the 1990s had a very similar if less dramatic effect. Firms converged on a benchmarked standard, and industry margins fell: in the case of desk top computers, from well over 50% of sales price in the 1980s to around 4% at the turn of the century. No firm could stand aside from this process, but nobody except the consumer did well from it.)
States have relied on income, speciality and general sales taxes for the bulk of their revenues, with corporation tax yielding relatively little. If employment by companies is to fall and states are expected to subsidise lives, one way or the other, this formula will have to change.
We need to consider three important features of the world ahead.
In review: change will be enacted in a global cauldron which nobody controls, in which automation will be a general truism and in which the emerging nations will be fielding more graduate workers than the old rich world has citizens. Nation states can do little to attract new initiatives but a great deal to repel them. (Offers such as tax breaks lead to rapid races to the bottom, as every nation is forced to join in.) Policy makers operate in a tight box, therefore, the edges of which are defined by best practice as shared amongst industries, regulators and state service professionals.
And in all of this, automation may be having the perverse effects with which we began: slow growth, declining profitability and employment. Capacity may be much expanded, but static national incomes imply deflation.
There is a further complication to consider. Cities are now the focus of the world economy. As automation severs the link between population centres and manufacture, what is done in cities will be increasing intangible, carried out by highly educated services workers who earn high salaries. Cities will continue to price out anyone who does not fit into this category, or offer services to them. The gap between the national elites and the non-participant hinterland will grow: a cultural, social, economic and political gap. the typical New Yorker expresses attitudes and ambitions that more closely match those head in London than either of those country's hinterlands. Britain's South finances life in the rest of the country; as does the Isle de France, the Chinese and US coasts, the Tokyo sprawl. Wealth generation is highly focused in every one of these.
The current model of "one nation" welfare is that each country taxes its economic uplands and redistributes this wealth nationally, as services and as welfare, such as pensions. In the stagnant world that automation may bring, where cities belong more to specialised organisational clouds than they do to nation states, how long can that persist? How long can the old rich world behave as it did when it had a monopoly on everything, from military power to technology, culture to economic strength, when it no longer has a hold on any of those? If its citizens plunder their cities, the engine will soon stop turning. If they neglect their hinterland, democracy will soon elect unfortunately leaders. Something has to give.